Since we were very young, we—or at least those of us raised
in functional households—were always told to “play fair.”
It was a sort of amorphous instruction, that covered a lot
of different territory. It went far beyond just not
cheating at games, to touch on many other aspects of day-to-day life, such as not ganging up on someone, either
physically or socially, not taking advantage of another’s disability, sharing
one’s good fortune, etc.
So most of us grow up with some concept of fairness.
Still, the fact that “fairness” is a broadly shared concept
doesn’t mean that it we all view the same things as “fair.” Watch two children split up a cupcake. It’s pretty likely that, if the pastry is cut
in a lopsided way, with one piece noticeably smaller than the other, the child
receiving that piece will start yelling something like “That’s not fair! He got the big half!”
We’ve all seen that happen, and probably said something
similar back in our younger days.
But, unless the child who received the larger piece is atypically
empathetic, or raised in a very caring and principled home—and, perhaps, not
even then—it’s pretty likely that such child will not be the first one to complain
about the division being unfair.
And that sort of thing pretty quickly trickles down into
fisheries issues.
The
Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act uses the word “fair,”
as well as derivatives such as “fairly” and “unfair,” a total of 22 times, and
uses the closely related word “equitable,” and its derivatives, 15 times more. But not everyone agrees on what those words
mean.
The disagreements emerge in different contexts, but there is
probably nothing in the fisheries arena that generates more claims of
unfairness than allocation decisions.
National standard 4, included in Magnuson-Stevens, states that
“Conservation and management measures shall not discriminate against
residents of different States. If it
becomes necessary to allocate or assign fishing privileges among various United
States fishermen, such allocations shall be (A) fair and equitable to all such
fishermen, (B) reasonably calculated to promote conservation, and (C) carried
out in such manner that no particular individual, corporation, or other entity
acquires an excessive share of such privileges.”
Despite the letter of the law, there can be real
disagreements about what a “fair and equitable” allocation of fishing
privileges looks like. In that regard,
it would seem that the simplest case to make is that allocating all of the harvest
of a particular species to one sector, and denying the other sector any share
of the landings—for example, so-called “gamefish” laws that outlaw commercial
harvest—is clearly unfair, and unable to survive a national standard 4
challenge.
But that’s not the case.
The commercial sector probably didn’t consider the court
decision any more “fair” than the regulations themselves, but it remains the
law of the land.
The fact that a regulation may have a disparate impact on
different sectors does not, by itself, create a national standard 4 issue. In
Alaska Factory Trawler Association v. Baldridge, trawlers and pot
fishermen challenged a regulation that allocated most of the Gulf of Alaska sablefish
catch to the longline fishery, and would eventually completely phase out the
use of fish pots in certain regions. The
court found against the plaintiffs, deciding that the management measure represented
a reasonable way to address gear conflicts, that the reduced trawl quota reflected
Advisory Panel comments, and so had a rational basis, and that social and
economic benefits, and so the overall benefit to the nation, would accrue from
the action, even though it did, to some degree discriminate against the trawl
and pot sectors.
Once again, it’s hard to believe that the trawler and pot
fishermen found the court’s decision fair.
However, it still stands as an important legal precedent.
Yet there can still be times when courts find that real,
actionable discrimination exists. In
Guindon v. Pritzker, a court found that a reallocation of red snapper
that favored the recreational sector was unfair, after NMFS adopted a Gulf of
Mexico Fishery Management Council decision to base allocation on years when the
commercial fishery was bound by a hard-poundage quota, and so could not increase
its landings, while the recreational sector was only governed by a “soft”
recreational harvest limit which that sector could, and often did, exceed, with
few consequences ensuing. Allowing the
recreational sector to benefit from chronically exceeding its harvest limit,
while the commercial sector suffered because it remained within its quota, was a step too far for
the court, which ruled that the reallocation was unfair, violated national
standard 4, and was thus invalid.
Still, despite cases like Guindon v. Pritzker, courts are
generally slow to find unfairness in federal management measures. The East Coast summer flounder fishery is a
case in point.
A
2018 benchmark stock assessment observed that
“…summer flounder are shifting northeast over time, and this
shift has continued in recent years…the shift northward is evident even in
small fish. Indeed, recruits appear to
be shifting northward at a faster rate than spawners, suggesting that they are
not merely tracking the expansion of spawners northward. There are apparent changes in spatial
distribution of summer flounder over the past four decades with a general shift
northward and eastward. Spatial
expansion is more apparent in the years of greater abundance since about 2000, although
it has continued even with the most recent declines in biomass.”
But when we look at the distribution of commercial summer
flounder allocation, we find that states’ initial allocations are based on
landings during the period 1980-1989, effectively setting states shares’ based
on where the fish were four decades ago, before the “general shift northward
and eastward,” noted in the stock assessment, began.
The Mid-Atlantic Fishery Management Council has recently
agreed to allocate a few more fish to the northern states if—and only
if—the commercial allocation exceeds 9.55 million pounds in any particular
year. However, in the upcoming 2024
season, the commercial quota will not reach that benchmark, so the basic
allocation described above will apply.
From that situation, we see two different concepts of “fairness”
emerge.
Fishermen in the northern states believe that it is unfair
to manage commercial summer flounder fishermen with quotas based on forty-year-old
data, that don’t reflect the current patterns of summer flounder abundance. At least one state, New York, has unsuccessfully
sued NMFS over the issue, while Senator
Charles Schumer (D-NY), as recently as 2021, introduced legislation titled the “Fluke
Fairness Act,” which included findings that
“The fishery management plan for summer flounder does not
account for regional changes in the location of the fluke stock even though the
stock has moved further to the north and changes in effort by anglers along the
East Coast,”
and
“The States have been locked in a management system based on
data collected from 1981 to 1989, thus, the summer flounder stock is not being
managed using the best available science and modern fishery management
techniques.”
Such findings generally sum up the feelings of fishermen
throughout the northern end of the summer flounder’s range, who feel that it is
grossly unfair to deny them access to fish sitting right off their ports,
simply because, forty years ago, those fish happened to be somewhere else.
“people have invested in licenses and businesses related to
this fishery. Changing allocations will
affect business models and business plans,”
and also that
“with any allocation, there will be winners and losers…Reallocation
will bankrupt people in the south…Managers shouldn’t take what people have and
give it to other states.”
To them, fairness requires that allocations take on an
almost hereditary nature; once granted to a state, they pass down through the
generations of fishermen, unchanged and unchanging. Whatever happens out on the ocean, with
respect to the movements and abundance of fish, quotas must remain immutable.
Perhaps it all comes down to the fisherman’s comment that “with
any allocation, there will be winners and losers,” with the winners judging “fairness”
through one set of eyes, and the losers through another. Or, to fall back on an old aphorism, the
perceived fairness of a management action all depends on whose ox is being
gored.
Thus, we often see commercial fishermen feel that managers
unfairly favor the recreational sector, saying that while the commercial sector
provides food for people all across the nation, the recreational sector
consists largely of well-heeled people merely “playing” with the fish. At the same time, striped bass anglers have
complained that recent actions intended to reduce fishing mortality were
unfair, because while the specified reductions were taken from actual
recreational landings, commercial reductions were taken from the quota, a
fairly meaningless action given that the commercial sector, both overall and in
several states, does not come close to landing its entire quota in any event, and might not have to cut back its overall landings at all.
How one conceives "fairness" all depends on where one stands.
Thus, I always get uneasy when I hear people either support or oppose fisheries actions because of their perceived “fairness,” as fairness is an ephemeral concept at best, and one which is frequently reinterpreted, depending on how an action will impact a particular assortment of people.
As coldhearted as it might sound, I always favor decisions that are based solely on data, and not on emotionally fraught concepts like “fairness.” I view such things from one standpoint only: Will a particular management measure make it more or less likely that a stock will be maintained at a healthy, sustainable level of abundance in the long term?
Sometimes, to achieve that goal, someone—whether we define
that “someone” as individuals or an entire sector—is going to have to be hurt,
and perhaps sacrificed. It might seem very
unfair, but in the end, it could help to avert the greatest inequity of all—denying
future generations the opportunity to know and enjoy a healthy, vibrant, and
thriving sea.
NC commercial fishermen like to talk about "Fresh and Local" fish a lot. By the time NC trawlers steam from NC to NE to drag for summer flounder (and black sea bass). fish a few days and steam back, the fish are neither fresh, nor local. Reallocation of the quota to northern states would make for a better/fresher product for the owners of the resource-the consumers. It might be less expensive since there would be a significant fuel saving. I dont like the idea of NC folks losing their income, but it would be better for the resource and a lot easier to enforce the rule.
ReplyDeleteAs for fairness in regard to NC fishermen, recreational fishermen get a 2 week season to catch summer, southern and gulf flounder with a bag limit of 1 fish. This is due to Southern flounder being overfished. All flounder caught in the ocean by recreational fishermen are counted as Southern flounder and must be returned except for the two week season.
ReplyDeleteCommercial fishermen are allowed several million pounds of summer flounder and trip limits in the 10s of thousands of pounds. Shrimpers dragging in the ocean catching flounder incidentally are allowed to keep them as they are counted as summer flounder, even though most of them are Southern flounder. NC regulatory agencies do not think recreational fishermen can distinguish between the three species so the closed them all. How is this fair?
A good example of why "fairness" is such a difficult concept to deal with. You make a compelling case that the current NC management approach to southern flounder is unfair to the recreational sector. But I'll bet if you asked someone with a trawler, including the shrimp trawls, they would tell you that it would be unfair to shut down their directed fisheries for summer flounder or shrimp, because they can't help catching southern flounder in gear authorized for the other species, and it would not be fair to hold them responsible for something that isn't their "fault."
DeleteWhich is why I try to avoid fairness questions, and just ask things like "do we need time and area closures for ceertain gear in order to reduce southern flounder bycatch?" Such restrictions, which prohibited the use of small mesh trawls in certain areas of the upper Mid-Atlantic, made a big contribution to the recovery of the once-overfished scup population, which is now well over its biomass target. Yes, some trawler operators will be hurt, but in the end, the fish, and so the greater pujblic interest, would receive a benefit.
No one is saying to shut down the shrimp trawling because they catch Southern flounder. What is the problem is all the Southern flounder they catch ARE NOT COUNTED against the commercial Southern flounder quota (which is tiny due to overfished status), but against the Summer flounder quota which is in the millions of pounds. Recreationally caught flounder in the ocean are counted against their Southern flounder quota. Since the summer flounder have moved North most fish caught are not summers.
DeleteNo one may be calling for it now, but I raise the issue because it may make sense. If there is a time when southern flounder are particularly vulnerable to shrimp trawls, then a time and area closure may be necessary. If gear produces excessive bycatch of a depleted species, restrictions on the use of such gear could be indicated.
Delete